Back to index

Ep 59: Protectionism | The Seen and the Unseen


#
I often say that the greatest mechanism of social service, of improving the lives of
#
other people, is free markets.
#
Think about what happens in a market, now everyone has needs, those needs can be fulfilled
#
by others either out of benevolence or out of self-interest.
#
Now benevolence cannot be relied upon, but self-interest always can.
#
Let's say you are a greedy person, you are a sociopath who doesn't care about other
#
people.
#
In a free market the only way you can make money and fulfill your own needs is by fulfilling
#
someone else's need by making them better off.
#
Remember every transaction in a free market is a positive sum game, both people who transact
#
are better off or they would not transact in the first place.
#
So the only way you can make money for yourself is by adding value to somebody's life.
#
Markets are the mechanism that enable people to help themselves by helping others first.
#
The beauty and elegance of this is quite mind-blowing and it also stands to reason therefore that
#
the more someone messes with this mechanism, the more someone gets in the way, the more
#
harm they cause to society.
#
Remember the crux of markets, the reason they exist is a value that someone is trying to
#
add to the life of another human being.
#
Nothing should be allowed to get in the way of that.
#
Welcome to the Seen and the Unseen.
#
Our weekly podcast on economics, politics and behavioral science.
#
Please welcome your host, Amit Padma.
#
Welcome to the Seen and the Unseen.
#
Before we begin this episode, a word from our sponsors of this episode, which actually
#
demonstrates a point I was making about markets.
#
Indian Colors is a company that licenses art from contemporary Indian artists and adapts
#
it into objects of everyday use.
#
Now let's look at this from the consumer's point of view.
#
I am a lover of fine art.
#
I go to exhibitions once in a while, but I can't really afford to buy paintings to hang
#
in my house.
#
Indian Colors makes it affordable for an art lover like me to actually surround myself
#
with art.
#
The artists benefit too.
#
Normally artists get a one-time payment on their paintings, unlike authors who get royalties
#
for each copy of every book that is sold.
#
Well, with this model, in addition to what these artists might get for selling their
#
original paintings, they also get royalties for each product sold.
#
And after all of this, after the consumer and the artist benefit, after the company
#
has paid its employees and suppliers, the company itself may or may not make a profit.
#
In fact, when people talk of trickle-down economics, I point out how this is a strawman
#
argument.
#
In any free market, wealth always trickles up, not down.
#
Anyway, you can head on over to IndianColors.com Colors with an OU to check out their products.
#
They have home decor like cushion covers and table runners, accessories like tote bags,
#
and I love their wearables, their kaftans, shrugs, and strolls.
#
They have some funky new strolls up by Deepak Shinde and Dilip Sharma.
#
And their roster of artists includes luminaries like Sameer Mondal, Dhruvi Acharya, Brinda
#
Miller, Shruti Nelson, and Harin Vakil.
#
Show them your appreciation.
#
Use the code IVM20 for a 20% discount.
#
That's IVM20 at IndianColors.com Colors with an OU.
#
And now on with this episode.
#
My guest today is the economist Anupam Manoor, who works as a fellow at the Takshashila Institution
#
in Bangalore.
#
And we're going to talk about protectionism, a tendency that should really have died out
#
by this time in the 21st century, but is actually to my utter bewilderment on the rise.
#
Here's a conversation I had with Anupam.
#
Anupam, welcome to the scene in The Unseen.
#
Thanks, Amit.
#
It's an absolute pleasure to be here.
#
Anupam, tell me something.
#
Is protectionism on the rise worldwide?
#
The short answer is yes.
#
It is definitely on the rise.
#
There's various data points that kind of confirm this, especially in the big advanced economies
#
of the world.
#
Protectionism is on the rise.
#
And as it often does, it started with the economic downturn.
#
So historically, protectionism always raises its ugly head when you have a decline in income
#
or overall GDP.
#
And this is exactly what has happened since 2008.
#
Because in different countries, you have people saying that, you know, hey, what's the use
#
of trade if people at home, you know, middle class workers are losing their jobs, our incomes
#
aren't increasing.
#
And the intuitive thing is to sort of blame the foreigner in terms of whether trade or
#
whether immigration and ask for cut downs on those.
#
And that's kind of why Donald Trump also is such a big protectionist.
#
Precisely.
#
So you see the kind of parallel trend in politics and in economics.
#
So you have the entire political rhetoric, which I don't want to get into.
#
And then you have actual trade policy and so on, which has been geared towards more
#
inward looking sort of policies, right.
#
So for example, I mean, let me just throw this stat at you that in the EU since 2008,
#
almost half, which is about 49 percent of all trade policies have been kind of harmful
#
to global trade.
#
And in the US, there's been about 1297 economic precise economic policies which are actually
#
harmful to trade as against 206 policies which have been helpful to trade.
#
So this just kind of gives you an idea.
#
And you will stop the list, by the way, in the world over.
#
And this is happening in India as well.
#
Yeah.
#
India actually is second in the world with a net kind of harmful protectionist measures
#
of 458 since 2009.
#
And there's a common belief among people that hey, protectionism is good because one, it
#
supports local producers and therefore there are local jobs and, you know, so on and so
#
forth.
#
So what you're going to do in this episode is you're going to break down eight myths
#
around protectionism.
#
So let's start with myth number one.
#
OK.
#
So one of the most I mean, and I'm going to start brushing with as broad a stroke as possible.
#
The first popular myth is that protectionism is good for the economy, right.
#
And that kind of breaks down when you start looking at the various seen and unseen effect.
#
And I'm going to use the title of your show here.
#
It's not my show.
#
Busier's famous essay.
#
I mean, we're all inspired by that.
#
Of course.
#
So it essentially any kind of protectionism will start.
#
Firstly, it might have a few good short term effects, which is obviously why it's so popular.
#
But in the medium to long run, it obviously harms the producers, the consumers and overall
#
kind of jobs scenario and so on.
#
And ultimately, it starts hurting economic growth.
#
For example, just again, another statistic is that an increase of $1 in tariff revenue
#
can result in as much as a $2.16 fall in overall world exports and about a $0.73 drop in world
#
income.
#
So that's looking at as broad a stroke as possible.
#
But even if you look at country level, because there can always be an argument saying, OK,
#
it can be bad for the world.
#
I don't care.
#
But it can be good for my country.
#
That is, again, gone because a $1 increase in tariff revenue for each country leads to
#
about $0.66 decrease in overall GDP.
#
So that kind of tells you that right at the beginning that protectionism harms the economy.
#
So let's try to illustrate that with a hypothetical example.
#
Let's say that I manufacture mobile phones.
#
But no one's buying my mobile phones because better phones are coming from China and Asia
#
and America and so on.
#
And I'm like, no, I'm the local industry.
#
I'll provide local jobs.
#
I want the government to protect me.
#
And so I pay off my local congressmen or my whatever.
#
I'm an interest group.
#
I pay them off.
#
And they say, OK, Amit, we'll have a law that protects you and that leads to local jobs.
#
And they pass, let's say, 200% tariffs on foreign phones, which make me competitive.
#
And now people start buying my phones.
#
And I am a local manufacturer.
#
I'm benefiting.
#
I'm paying taxes in the economy.
#
And I'm employing people.
#
All seems hunky dory.
#
That's a scene effect.
#
What's the unseen here?
#
What happens?
#
It's really utopian in nature, right?
#
But if you break it down and if you look at the unseen effect, what actually happens is
#
that immediately when once an industry gets protection, they no longer have any incentives
#
to be productive or to increase productivity, to innovate, to expand, and generally be competitive
#
in the marketplace, right?
#
Because now you're no longer under threat.
#
You tend to take things a bit more lax.
#
That's the first kind of an incentive structure, how it plays out.
#
Right, also now because you have no kind of protection, basically your profit margins
#
and so on would be much higher than what it would normally be.
#
So your prices go up.
#
So domestic prices go up.
#
And now the consumers no longer have a choice of cheaper kind of import goods, right?
#
So you no longer also have, I mean, that choice is removed as well.
#
So what you'd end up with is much higher domestic prices, an industry which is not competitive
#
at all.
#
So there's no way that that industry can actually go out and export to the world market, right?
#
If you had let it be, then this probably industry could have, you know, the good ones at least
#
could have competed with the world market, grown and actually bought an export revenue.
#
But that's not happening anymore.
#
So the firm stays small, barely manages to kind of meet local demand and at much higher
#
costs.
#
An example of this comes from my childhood as I grew up in the 1980s.
#
And you know, you had one telecom company in the country that effectively, which was
#
MTNL, which was a government company.
#
Now, leave aside that it was a government company, but it was a protected marketplace.
#
And what that did was that if you wanted a telephone, there was a seven year waiting
#
list at times.
#
And today it's no longer a protected marketplace.
#
You have all kinds of foreign players in the market and you can get a mobile phone in five
#
minutes with all kinds of freebies and incentives for the consumer attached.
#
And people often don't see the consumer point of view of this, that let's say that I am
#
buying a mobile phone today for 3000 rupees.
#
But because you have these protectionist measures, I have the local guy, Amit Verma mobile phones,
#
which are available to me for 10,000.
#
Now that's 7,000 rupees that I would notionally be saving if I bought the foreign product.
#
If I had saved that, I would have also spent it in the local economy only.
#
I would have bought other things for it.
#
The money would have gone out into the economy, provided other jobs, which it is not providing
#
now and that's the unseen effect.
#
Exactly.
#
And far too often, I think, and this is an unfortunate aspect of this, is that you only
#
look at the kind of specific sector that you're trying to save, which is more often than not
#
in terms of protectionism is the producer.
#
But you completely ignore the kind of effect that it has on the consumer.
#
And as you said, the kind of consumer surplus is almost diminished when you bring in protectionism
#
and which, you know, when translated into reality means that they no longer have that
#
kind of extra disposable income that they would have had if you had cheaper alternatives.
#
So the amount of money that they would have spent on other things obviously reduces.
#
And that has a dual effect.
#
One effect is that because of the incentives that you spoke about, the local company doesn't
#
have the incentive to innovate.
#
And the other effect that it has is when the consumer would spend this money out in the
#
marketplace that would increase the effect for others to also innovate wherever they
#
were spending their money.
#
So overall innovation goes down across the board.
#
Yeah, innovation goes down, lots of inefficiencies creep in, overall productivity decreases.
#
And obviously all of this will have kind of a staggering effect on economic growth, right?
#
Right.
#
Let's move on to your second myth.
#
Okay.
#
The second myth is that protectionism should be removed only if it is reciprocated from
#
the other countries.
#
So what you mean by this is that let's say we have a tariff on products from China and
#
they have a tariff on products for India.
#
And the argument then goes that, hey, we should only remove our tariff on them if they remove
#
their tariff on us.
#
Yeah.
#
Because if not, you would feel completely cheated.
#
And especially again, your producers would feel cheated that, you know, we are not able
#
to compete in the marketplace in China.
#
Why are we allowing Chinese producers to compete here?
#
Absolutely.
#
So what's your response to this?
#
The response is actually that just unilateral reduction in trade barriers can have a huge
#
kind of impact on your economy, a positive impact on your economy.
#
Again, going back to this similar thread that we caught off in the previous myth is that
#
by reducing your trade barriers, what you essentially do is that you are making your
#
domestic firms a lot more competitive.
#
They are actually pressurizing them to innovate, to sustain themselves, to stay in the market
#
for as long as possible and so on.
#
And that has positive knock on effects on the entire economy.
#
But the other kind of curious thing that happens is that if you unilaterally decrease your
#
trade barrier, then the let's say the exporters in China would now suddenly want to take a
#
advantage of this.
#
And one of the ways to take advantage of that is by having easier imports.
#
So for example, again, if China wants to export mobile phones to India, they'd also want kind
#
of software and that they import, let's say from India, right?
#
So then they would create a lobby and they would force the Chinese government to reduce
#
the import tariffs on software, right?
#
So in this way, unilateral reduction in trade barriers always leads to kind of the reciprocal
#
later on.
#
So the later on, even if it didn't happen, it would be fine because people are benefiting.
#
Yes, yes.
#
Your consumers benefit.
#
And that's like the largest majority of this thing, right?
#
I mean, India, 73% of the GDP or so comes from consumption, you know, so just by that
#
one logic, it's good.
#
But let me also, again, throw another stat at you.
#
There was a study conducted of five big economies in the world, and out of which, as a result
#
of, you know, unilateral trade liberalization, and these were unique cases where they just
#
said we're going to remove all our trade barriers in respect to what the rest of the world does.
#
And this is, let's say, Singapore, Hong Kong, UAE, Chile, and Thailand.
#
And it was found that just this unilateral trade liberalization led to, you know, expansion
#
of 22 times of GDP for Singapore, 8 to 12 times for the other countries.
#
And this was over a span of 35 years.
#
Of course, it's a long period, but 22 times.
#
The figures are still staggering.
#
And one thing people often don't realize is that countries don't trade with other countries.
#
Individuals trade with individuals.
#
And now every trade is a positive sum game.
#
Two people trade with each other only because both of them benefit.
#
And the extent to which you get in their way is the extent to which you reduce the benefit
#
for both.
#
So a government is actually harming its citizens every time, produces friction in between a
#
transaction between any two consenting individuals, and therefore when the government has a trade
#
barrier in place between, say, you, the consumer in India and me, the producer in China, it's
#
not that it's harming me, it's harming you as well.
#
Absolutely.
#
I think this approach towards trade, that it's not a zero sum game, is something that
#
the policymakers across the world don't see at all.
#
I mean, they tend to think of trade as a positive, I mean, as a zero sum game, that, you know,
#
if we are reducing our import tariffs, then we are actually helping someone else at the
#
cost of ourselves.
#
But it's often not the case.
#
I mean, consumers always look out for the best deal.
#
And importing isn't just, you know, your standard buying, but it's just from a foreigner.
#
So you know, consumers always look for a good deal and they want to buy from the place which
#
gives them the best deal.
#
So you're actually helping the consumer by not interfering with this at all.
#
You're helping the consumer find a great deal.
#
Let's move on to the third myth.
#
The third myth is that protectionism increases saving and investment in the economy.
#
So the corollary is that free trade would actually harm your saving and investment cycle
#
in the country.
#
And basis of that is that by having no kind of restrictions on import, consumers would
#
just go mad and buy everything from the world just because they can.
#
And again, this is a very, very stupid argument in its essence, right?
#
Because as I said, consumers would buy only if they have the money and if they want it
#
and if the price is right, they just, you know, and it's the same as buying domestically
#
or from internationally.
#
And in the same way, I mean, every consumer has a set of incentives and a certain set
#
of, you know, planning that they do for their own personal income.
#
So they'll spend as much as they can, they'll save as much as they can, and so on.
#
So if a country as a whole is spending more than it is saving, then the problem is not
#
with imports.
#
The problem is with the domestic financial sector and so on and so forth, right?
#
So actually, increasing trade barriers or decreasing trade barriers have absolutely
#
no effect on your saving and investment cycle.
#
In fact, what I would argue is that it makes the situation worse because if you're putting
#
up trade barriers and if you're forcing your consumers to spend more on, you know, costlier
#
products in the economy, then that means that you're essentially taking away that extra
#
bit of disposable income that they perhaps could have saved.
#
Saved or spent somewhere.
#
And the myth like that, the way you articulated it, also condescends to consumers.
#
They assume that you're like sheep who don't know what they're doing and can't take rational
#
decisions in their own interest, while the fact of the matter is that every consumer,
#
you know, we're using that general term, but every consumer is basically you and me.
#
You're perfectly capable of making decisions in our own interest.
#
We should have the right to do so.
#
And the government job is to get out of the way so that we have as many choices available
#
to us as possible.
#
Absolutely.
#
And again, if what the government has to look at and far more often than not, if there is
#
actually depletion of savings and investment means that your domestic kind of, you know,
#
financial sector is not doing all right, that there are no proper avenues for saving or
#
there's no proper avenues for investment, which is why people tend to just consume the
#
entire amount that they get because they don't have any trust in the economy to do well in
#
the future.
#
Right.
#
And honestly, if you just enable a free market and you don't put entry barriers and even
#
the domestic finance sector would respond to the demand and the problem won't arise
#
in the first place.
#
Precisely.
#
Yeah.
#
Let's move on to myth number four.
#
Okay.
#
So myth number four is that protectionism will improve trade balance.
#
And this is something that, you know, politicians and policymakers in whatever level of capacity
#
that they understand, somehow care a lot about, though they, you know, my intuitive guess
#
is that they really don't understand a lot about balance of payment statistics and how
#
the whole thing works.
#
But having a negative, you know, or a trade deficit with another country, and especially
#
if it is, you know, in not very favorable terms in the geopolitical space is seen as
#
a really bad thing.
#
And let's take the example of India and China.
#
You would remember that, you know, there were calls for banning of imports from China because
#
of that India has a huge trade deficit with China.
#
And this is, again, a phenomenon that has absorbed the world over.
#
US lawmakers have forever been asking for protection against Japanese imports.
#
And that's because they believe that US runs a huge trade deficit against Japan.
#
And that can't be good for their kind of relative economic power.
#
But honestly, again, it has nothing to do with trade barriers.
#
But it's to do with what each country has a comparative advantage in.
#
So, India might actually be better off just importing a lot of things from China than
#
trying to, you know, manufacture it domestically because China obviously has a comparative
#
advantage in the manufacturing sector, right?
#
So we're just probably better off importing those things and allocating our scarce resources
#
towards something else that we're good at and then trying to export that to the world,
#
right?
#
But in order to, you know, no single time in the history of, you know, at least a counted
#
world do we have a situation where trade barriers has actually gone on to improve a country's
#
trade balance.
#
Always, we find that the negative is the opposite is true.
#
And even if that wasn't the case, why should it matter if you have a trade deficit?
#
Like I remember this very old column by Tim Halford, I think more than a decade ago,
#
but a memorable one where he pointed out that, look, you probably have a trade deficit with
#
your maidservant.
#
You buy her services, but she buys nothing from you.
#
And this is a trade deficit that is perpetual and keeps growing.
#
Is it a problem?
#
I don't think so.
#
Both of you benefit.
#
Yeah, precisely.
#
Yeah, I couldn't have put it better, but there's, there's been this kind of alarmist viewpoint
#
about trade deficit in the world.
#
And I don't know why, because people are not as concerned about fiscal deficit, for example,
#
the layman at least, but somehow trade deficit get, people get really touchy and emotional
#
about it.
#
Exactly.
#
And it should be the other way around.
#
But yeah, in the US, especially you've had a concern about US trade deficit with Japan
#
before and now with China and they've been called for protectionist measures.
#
Let's move on to point number five.
#
What's myth number five about protectionism?
#
Okay.
#
The fifth popular myth regarding protectionism is that it will help create jobs in your domestic
#
industry.
#
And I know we touched upon this separately, but again, it's one of the things that's been
#
used over and again by world leaders for instituting any kind of trade barriers.
#
Right.
#
I mean, again, back to the simple example, if instead of buying a mobile phone for 3000
#
and buying it for 10,000, that 7,000 surplus I would otherwise have had would have gone
#
into the economy and created productive jobs.
#
That's no longer happening because all of that money is going to the producer in question
#
who probably has a much bigger profit margin and might well be paying his workers less.
#
Yeah.
#
So it's a complete myth.
#
It works the other way.
#
It works the other way.
#
So this is especially true in, you know, industries which have linkages, forward and backward
#
linkages.
#
So I think one of the most favored kind of industry in the world for protecting is the
#
steel industry.
#
But actually no other kind of policy move makes more harm than trying to protect the
#
steel industry because let's say you slap import duty on steel so that you can help
#
your domestic steel producers.
#
And of course, the number of people involved currently in a job in one of these steel firms.
#
But what you end up doing is that again, you raise the prices of steel, et cetera, et cetera,
#
and basically it becomes uncompetitive and so on.
#
And now let's say automobiles, which actually hires a lot more people now are no longer
#
competitive because it has to buy expensive steel from your domestic manufacturers.
#
Now your automobile industry will lose out and the number of people there who are currently
#
employed may start losing their jobs.
#
So in terms of net effect on jobs, it's definitely negative.
#
Not just that.
#
So what the initial scene effect is that, hey, you're protecting some jobs in the steel
#
industry, but the unseen effect is that, hey, because the price of steel goes up, you are
#
actually either losing jobs in the automobile industry or jobs that would otherwise have
#
been there because of the growth are not coming about.
#
And that in turn reduces the demand for steel and could eventually end up hurting jobs.
#
So what this does is just as trade is a positive sum game, this kind of protectionism becomes
#
a negative sum game where both players lose out.
#
Yeah, absolutely.
#
And it's just not that to add one extra layer to that by providing, let's say protectionism
#
to the incumbent, he gets the kind of perfect conditions for creating a sort of monopoly
#
or oligopoly with the few existing ones.
#
And there's no way a new entrant can come in.
#
So under normal circumstances, you know, if there is normal profits, you would have new
#
entrant coming into the steel industry who would hire a lot more, which again is vanished
#
now because of the protectionism.
#
Exactly.
#
So it has the opposite impact to what the myth would suggest it does.
#
Let's move on to myth number six.
#
So the myth number six is that protectionism saves the economy from dumping.
#
And let's just look at what dumping means, which is, I mean, there's no universally kind
#
of agreed definition of what dumping is, but largely it would be that if another country
#
is exporting its products to you at extremely low rates, which is deemed to be unfair and
#
we look at what unfair is later on, but it's exporting at unfair prices, which is lower
#
than what it's selling at its domestic market.
#
So that is generally called dumping.
#
So basically it wants to capture your market, even if it undergoes a loss for the time period
#
so that it can have a monopoly later on.
#
Give me an illustrative example of this.
#
Okay.
#
So let's take the example of China and India again.
#
If China is exporting, let's say alarm clocks to India, and it is selling at $10 in China
#
for, you know, a piece, and then it's selling the same alarm clock at $5 in India, then
#
that is considered to be dumping because now the Chinese producer there is willing to take
#
a hit on its profit margin so that it can actually conquer the market here.
#
And this is frowned upon in all kinds of policy circles and as well as by the way, WTO and
#
so on.
#
And one can see why, because the logical thing that you think here is that, Hey, you know,
#
they are dumping their goods here and because of that local alarm clock manufacturers are
#
getting screwed.
#
Yeah.
#
Now, again, there's a couple of ways to look at this.
#
Now one, your local alarm clock manufacturers might never be that good and they might, you
#
know, not really survive this onslaught.
#
Sure.
#
But then your consumers are getting, you know, alarm clocks at $5 instead of the $10, which
#
they would have otherwise paid.
#
So it's great for the consumers.
#
Now you have to look at the net kind of benefit sometimes, you know, the kind of gain to consumers
#
can outweigh the loss from the producers.
#
But even then it would be deemed as, you know, unfair and it's fair to think of it that way.
#
Now the problem is that you also, this is going into technical definitions, right?
#
It looks at what the cost of production is and if it sells at, you know, a price lower
#
than the cost of production, the problem, and this is even, let's say in a market as
#
analytically rigorous and regulatory, which has got sound regulatory principles like the
#
US, they talk about cost of production, but don't mention whether it's total cost, whether
#
it's marginal cost, whether it's average cost.
#
And I've looked at the definition of dumping in according to the US rule book, which is
#
problematic.
#
So that's the problem with the definition.
#
But let's look at what happens in reality.
#
In the US, what you would have is you'd have a local producer who would go up to the regulator
#
and says, listen, I think I'm being shortchanged here because I'm losing out on the competition
#
because another country is kind of, you know, dumping and it would have to file a suit,
#
you know, formal complaint of sorts.
#
And then the Ministry of Commerce or Department of Commerce would actually take a look at
#
it.
#
And there's another body which also takes a look at it.
#
Now, both of them come at some kind of subjective discretion, you know, and subjective and a
#
discretionary kind of judgment on whether dumping has happened or not.
#
And far more often than not, what it is, is that the lobbying would take over and then
#
declare something as dumping.
#
And that would lead to slapping off, you know, import duty on whatever is being dumped.
#
So this is what actually takes place in reality.
#
And because of the kind of nebulous definitions, lack of clear procedure or laws relating to
#
dumping, you have countries all over the world when they don't like, you know, some kind
#
of imports and the domestic producers getting hurt, they just say this is dumping.
#
And then the WTO can't do anything about it because, you know, according to the WTO rules,
#
you can take protective measures against dumping.
#
To just go back to that fundamental point, I'd say that, hey, you know, why is dumping
#
used in a pejorative sense?
#
If a guy in China is manufacturing alarm clocks for $6 and selling them to me at five, I am
#
benefiting.
#
Your local consumer is benefiting.
#
Let the Chinese guy take the hit.
#
Precisely.
#
I don't see that.
#
And this is if you kind of want to broaden the horizon, this is the same kind of argument
#
I'm making against, you know, predatory pricing and so on.
#
If Uber wants to spend a lot of its VC money and give me extremely cheap rides, I'm very
#
happy with it.
#
I don't see why I should complain against that at all.
#
If something, you know, if someone wants to give me something for free or at extremely
#
low prices.
#
And I think at the heart of this is a fundamental misunderstanding about markets.
#
Now, what are markets?
#
I call, you know, people privilege producers so much, which of course it would because
#
producers are the ones who are the special interest groups who are funding all politics.
#
But the truth is the consumer is at the heart of all markets.
#
I regard free markets as a greatest form of social service because what does a market
#
does?
#
It satisfies the needs of people.
#
Free trade is satisfying someone's needs.
#
If you just put the consumer, the heart at all of your policy and cater to getting the
#
greatest benefit out to consumers as as possible, then all of these things wouldn't be taboos.
#
The dumping, bring it on, bro.
#
The entire approach towards policymaking would change.
#
I mean, not just, you know, international trade policy and so on, but yeah, domestic
#
policies.
#
The entire thing would change.
#
And as to how you'd look at it, absolutely, I agree with you on that one.
#
But let's get to the heart of this anti-dumping kind of stance.
#
A lot of the anti-dumping measures are actually done as an equalizer of or to create a level
#
playing field.
#
So that goes against the very nature of why people trade.
#
People trade because of comparative advantage.
#
Now, you have something that I want and I have something that you want and thus it's
#
beneficial for us to trade.
#
But if you want to create that level playing field saying, you know, Amit, I'm going to
#
give you exactly the same resources and Anupama, I'm going to give you the exactly same resources.
#
And then what is our incentive to trade at all?
#
That sounds like a crazy dystopia because then all positive sum games, which is to say
#
all trades stop and we stop benefiting.
#
I mean, here's the thing.
#
Trade happens because two people value two things separately.
#
So when I buy a cup of coffee from you, let's say your Starbucks, I buy a cup of coffee
#
from you.
#
I value the coffee more than the 180 rupees I'm paying for it.
#
You can make out I buy it all Americanos.
#
And you value the 180 rupees more than the cup of coffee.
#
Both of us benefit.
#
And if you want a level playing field, then, you know, we eventually move to a sort of
#
socialist dystopia where you don't get my money and I don't get your coffee and we're
#
both worse off than we're both worse off.
#
Yeah.
#
So that is where anti dumping kind of thinking comes from.
#
And it's bizarre for me.
#
So let's move on to the next myth then, myth number seven, myth number seven, which is
#
protectionism will help your infant industries.
#
And by Joe, I think this is again a big one, but let's try and keep it brief.
#
The thinking behind this is that there are certain industries which have or even certain
#
firms which are just starting off in your economy and you see great potential of good
#
that the firm will do in the future.
#
And thus you want to kind of protect it now, because if you expose it to the evil kind
#
of international traders, then it will get completely decimated and you will lose out.
#
So to go back to our earlier hypothetical example, I start making mobile phones.
#
I am a infant industry, but at the start when I'm on my learning curve, I can't compete
#
with the Chinese and American giants unless you put tariffs on them.
#
So I have sales and I have the space to grow.
#
And one day I become a giant myself.
#
That's the thinking.
#
Yeah.
#
And once you become a giant, then you can come, you know, lower the trade barriers,
#
though, by the way, that's never happened in the world.
#
So that's the infant industry argument.
#
But I think the same set of arguments that we've been talking about apply here.
#
The minute you kind of protect an industry, it loses all the incentive to grow and to
#
compete in the marketplace.
#
And we've seen this the world over.
#
But again, if you want to take India as an example, we did this from 1950s onwards until
#
1990s.
#
We protected all our industries from the outside world.
#
And in fact, we even protected certain domestic industries from other domestic industries.
#
In fact, they started under Nehru and the term people use for it, import substitution.
#
Import substitution.
#
So the whole thinking was that, OK, so instead of importing all of this, let's divert our
#
resources and try to build these things ourselves.
#
And then these industries will grow and then can compete in the marketplace.
#
None of that has happened.
#
And again, the same kind of thinking, as I said, applies in the domestic industry.
#
So you want to kind of delegate a certain set of jobs for small industries.
#
You want a certain set of tasks and a certain set of products for micro industries and so
#
on and protect them from the bigger industries.
#
All sorts of protectionism of the sort has not worked.
#
And I doubt it will ever work because, again, the incentives to kind of grow and compete
#
in the marketplace will not be there.
#
And irrespective of how much you protect it, you will always end up with an infant.
#
So this kind of protectionism or using tax policy to protect or using import duties to
#
protect it, it's more like putting an industry on ventilator, right?
#
It's not sustainable in the long run.
#
It's just about, you know, you can save it for a day or two or probably years in terms
#
of an economy's lifespan, but definitely not sustainable in the long run.
#
That's very well put.
#
What strikes me as particularly perverse about this is that while the intention is good,
#
both the scene effect and the unseen effect are bad.
#
The scene effect is that the infant industry remains an infant on ventilator, as you so
#
eloquently put it, and doesn't grow at all because the incentives are all messed up.
#
And the unseen effect, what we don't see is that the value that the consumer would have
#
saved, they would have spent that on something.
#
And we don't see that.
#
And that would have given rise to more infant industries which would have grown.
#
And we don't see any of that.
#
Absolutely.
#
And the other common analogy used here is that, you know, there are infants and there
#
are dwarfs.
#
Right.
#
Infants actually grow up and become really big someday and can do a lot of product.
#
But here we turn our infants into dwarfs.
#
We turn our infants into dwarfs.
#
They'll always remain short, which means that they'll never grow.
#
And this is seen in kind of India's manufacturing sector.
#
You have this massive missing middle, right?
#
Because we always keep protecting our small industries.
#
We never actually allow them to grow.
#
And we, of course, I don't want to get into labor laws and, you know, all the allied factors,
#
but the when you look at it, you are not giving any kind of incentives for the small industries
#
to grow up and become the big industry that you would always hope.
#
And because we force our infants to be dwarfs and because we have that missing middle, that's
#
a big part of the jobs crisis that we face currently in India today.
#
Exactly.
#
You know, we talk about, hey, you know, there is this big jobs crisis.
#
What do we do about it?
#
But the causes for it are something that have been coming down the line for 60 years and
#
which continue.
#
And no government has ever taken the right stand on this.
#
No, I think it's too courageous a move to, you know, use as minister this thing.
#
It just seen as too courageous.
#
So even in 91, when we liberalized, we liberalized parts of trade and so on.
#
But there are, you know, factor markets that we didn't touch at all.
#
But I think we are digressing far too much.
#
Yeah.
#
And partly because partly because they're so unintuitive that, you know, voters understand
#
into it.
#
Voters see the world in an intuitive, zero sum kind of way.
#
And to talk about, you know, the positive sumness of trade or removing, you know, all
#
of this is very unintuitive in a sense.
#
All the myths that you are talking about today are things that you would naturally intuitively
#
believe.
#
Yeah.
#
And you know, and you have to fight hard to get past the thinking on that.
#
Let's move on to myth number eight.
#
Okay.
#
So myth number eight and the final myth here is that protectionism is necessary for developing
#
economies.
#
And this is a very peculiar charge that's put up that, you know, the reason why, let's
#
say the WTO or even sometimes, you know, IMF World Bank and the big institutions or even
#
the U.S. pushes for removal of trade barriers is that it actually helps the developed countries
#
while it completely harms the developing countries.
#
Now, you know, my one kind of simple argument against this is that just as there is no kind
#
of Indian physics as against, you know, U.S. physics, there is no Indian economics and
#
U.S. economics.
#
Right.
#
The principles of trade and principles of economics is exactly the same, whether it's
#
for developing countries or developed countries.
#
I mean, it's a positive sum game everywhere, everywhere.
#
So just just that is, you know, the kind of starting point.
#
But again, we can look at certain data which which is done by, you know, I mean, of course,
#
conspiracy theorists will cry foul.
#
But again, I've got some data by a study done by World Bank.
#
And it says that, you know, by reducing kind of your trade barriers and going towards liberalization
#
of in the goods and services market would help, you know, average real incomes in developed
#
countries increase by point seven six percent.
#
But it will help developing economies increase the real incomes by one point three percent
#
per year.
#
So it actually shows that developing economies have a lot more to gain than developed economies.
#
I mean, everybody gains from trade, but developing economies gain more so because you can leverage
#
the comparative advantage that much precisely.
#
And again, another small data point is that newly developing economies.
#
Right.
#
And these are newly industrializing economies that have just kind of come on the scene.
#
They tend to gain as much as three to six percent of GDP year on year by liberalizing
#
their trade regimes.
#
So the kind of data is out there, but because it's unintuitive to kind of understand this
#
and it's easy to cry foul saying that, you know, the developed world wants this so that
#
they can dump their goods onto us and kill our infant industries.
#
It's very hard for people to see it this way.
#
And that kind of rhetoric is very popular.
#
I mean, I think you've pretty much covered all the myths that I can think of regarding
#
protectionism and and still the fallacies persist.
#
Why is that?
#
Oh, that is a very difficult answer for me to.
#
I mean, you know, for me to address, but I honestly wouldn't know because I think most
#
of these myths, as you rightly said, they're intuitive to understand.
#
And this is the same thing with any other kind of economic policies.
#
Right.
#
Why are price controls so popular?
#
Right.
#
Because on the face of it, it seems that this is something good for me.
#
Right.
#
As a consumer, let's say you would be happy with the price control in the beginning because
#
you don't firstly have the vision for long term, you know, to see what would happen in
#
the long term.
#
But you can see immediately that the amount you're spending decreases.
#
So you're immediately happy.
#
But then, you know, economics tells you that there are lots of unintended price controls
#
always lead to shortages and which perpetuate themselves for the long term.
#
But I think one essential thing here is that that short and long term kind of dichotomy
#
that exists.
#
Right.
#
I think most of these things would kind of lead to some kind of positive effect in the
#
short term.
#
If you protect the steel industry for the next two years, it might actually grow.
#
And then politicians would happily say that, listen, this is because of my trade policy.
#
What for me?
#
I brought this policy.
#
I bought this about and it saved the kind of jobs that would have probably gone out
#
if you had let the industry die.
#
But then again, again, you know, who has the capacity to think and analyze and see for
#
the next 10 years what's going to happen to the entire steel industry and how many.
#
And it's also easier to kind of look at the factual than the counterfactual.
#
Because most of these arguments are counterfactual in nature.
#
You know, if you hadn't done that, you could probably generate 10x more jobs in the future.
#
How can people believe that?
#
And also politicians are focused on the short terms as always in election around the corner.
#
So it's much easier to sort of tout either an intended benefit or even sometimes a short
#
term scene effect and say that, hey, you know, this is what I have done.
#
And politicians don't care about what happens 10, 15 years down the line that someone else's
#
problem, right?
#
You know, so this has been a great episode, a great conversation where you've brought
#
forth a number of economic reasonings against protectionism.
#
All of those seem completely flawless and have absolutely no holes as far as I can see.
#
I want to end with making a moral case.
#
I think there are lots of people who would agree that what two consenting adults do with
#
each other is their business.
#
No one should interfere.
#
They would certainly agree, especially a lot of left liberals would agree when this is
#
in a private domain, you know, two consenting adults in their bedroom, they can do whatever
#
they want in our daily interactions, we can do whatever they want.
#
But when it comes to trade, suddenly we come up with all these fallacious series and we
#
say that, no, we should interfere.
#
And no, I think if it is immoral in the first case to interfere, it is immoral in every
#
case to interfere.
#
Consenting adults interact with each other because both of them benefit in various ways,
#
which includes financial ways in the marketplace.
#
Individuals trade with each other, countries don't.
#
We should never forget that.
#
Absolutely.
#
I think even before all of these eight myths, though, your point is probably the first amongst
#
it, right?
#
If economic freedom should be kind of attractive in and of its own right, a moral imperative.
#
Yes.
#
Anupam, thanks so much for being on the show.
#
I've learned so much from you today.
#
Oh, absolutely.
#
I loved it.
#
I'm a senior.
#
If you enjoyed this episode, you can follow Anupam on Twitter at Anupam Malur.
#
You can follow me at Amit Verma.
#
Archival's episode of the Scene and the Unseen are available at sceneunseen.in.
#
Thank you for listening.
#
The Scene and the Unseen is co-produced by Indus Vox Media Podcasts and you can check
#
out other IVM Podcast shows on the Rapper website, especially a new one called Akansha
#
Against Harassment.
#
Hosted by Akansha Srivastava, this show discusses cybercrimes and how to make the internet a
#
safe place.
#
For one, you can stop browsing and start listening.
#
It's out every Thursday.
#
You can see more of her species on ivmpodcasts.com, your one stop destination where you can check
#
out the coolest Indian podcasts.
#
Happy Listening.